Department of Economics University of Louisville Seal
   
Yong Chao
 
   
 Assistant Professor
 
 
Research Interests
 
  Applied Microeconomics Theory, Industrial Organization, Behavioral Economics, Antitrust and Regulatory Policies
 
Current Research Topics
 
  All-Units Discounts, Two-Sided Markets, Behavior-Based Pricing Strategy
   
Publications
   
  ¡°Strategic Effects of Three-Part Tariffs under Oligopoly.¡± International Economic Review 54(3): 977-1015.
 
  Abstract
 
  A three-part tariff refers to a pricing scheme consisting of a fixed fee, a free allowance of units up to which the marginal price is zero, and a positive per-unit price for additional demand beyond that allowance. The three-part tariff and its variations are commonly used in both final-goods and intermediate-goods markets. Recently, the offering of three-part tariffs and the like by dominant firms has become a prominent antitrust issue (e.g., U.S. v. Microsoft Corp. and AMD v. Intel). Existing studies have focused on monopoly models, interpreting the three-part tariff as a price discrimination device. In this paper, I investigate strategic effects of three-part tariffs in a sequential-move game and offer an equilibrium theory of three-part tariffs in a competitive context. I show that, compared with linear pricing equilibrium and two-part tariff equilibrium, a three-part tariff always strictly increases the dominant firm¡¯s (the leader¡¯s) profit when competing against a rival (the follower) with substitute products, in the absence of usual price discrimination motive. To explore the effects of a three-part tariff on welfare, I further perform comparative statics analysis using general differentiated linear demand system. I show that the competitive effect of a three-part tariff in contrast to linear pricing depends on the degree of substitutability between products: Competition is intensified when two products are more differentiated, yet softened when two products are more substitutable. This is in stark contrast with the competitive scenario posed by a two-part tariff: A two-part tariff always enhances competition and gives the highest total surplus of these three pricing schemes. Moreover, the rival firm always gets hurt in both profit and quantity sale when the dominant firm switches from linear pricing to a two-part tariff, yet it enjoys higher profit when the dominant firm moves from a two-part tariff to the more ornate three-part tariff, despite the fact that its quantity and market share are decreased even further. My findings offer a new perspective on three-part tariffs, a perspective which could help antitrust enforcement agencies distinguish the exclusionary three-part tariff from the pro-competitive one.
   
 
  Abstract
 
  We extend the traditional literature on bundling and the burgeoning literature on two-sided markets by presenting a theoretical monopoly model of mixed bundling in the context of the portable video game console market¡ªa prototypical two-sided market. We show that the monopoly platform¡¯s dominant strategy is to offer a mixed bundle rather than pure bundle or no bundle. Deviating from both traditional bundling literature and standard two-sided markets literature, we find that, under mixed bundling, both the standalone console price on the consumer side and the royalty rate on the game developer side are lower than their counterparts under independent pricing equilibrium. In our setting, mixed bundling acts as a price discrimination tool segmenting the market more efficiently as well as functions as a coordination device helping solve ¡°the chicken or the egg¡± problem in two-sided markets. After theoretically evaluating the impact mixed bundling has on prices and welfare, we further test the model predictions with new data from the portable video game console market in the early to middle 2000s, during which Nintendo was a monopolist. We employ a reduced form approach, and find empirical support for all theoretical predictions.
   
  “Pay-What-You-Want Pricing: Can It Be Profitable?” with Jose Fernandez and Babu Nahata Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics (Forthcoming)
    Abstract
    Using a game theoretic framework, we show that not only can pay-what-you-want (PWYW) pricing generate positive profits, but it can also be more profitable than charging a fixed price to all consumers. Further, whenever it is more profitable, it is also Pareto-improving. We derive conditions in terms of two cost parameters, namely the marginal cost of production and the psychological cost of the consumer for paying too little compared to her reference price.
     The paper makes the following contributions to the existing literature. First, we endogenize the choice of pricing strategies—PWYW vs. fixed price. Thus rather than solely focusing on the profitability of PWYW pricing, we evaluate its profitability vis-a-vis uniform pricing. To the best of our knowledge this has not been done so far theoretically. Second, we specify consumer utility to account for both economic and behavioral considerations. We show that when marginal cost is low and behavioral considerations are strong, then PWYW pricing can exploit the deadweight loss present under the uniform price to gain additional profit at the cost of serving some free riders. Therefore, PWYW pricing can be more profitable than charging a fixed price especially when the marginal cost is low and the deadweight loss is high. Third, we demonstrate PWYW pricing is more attractive when the cost of price setting is considerable or the market size is small.
   
Research Papers
   
 
  Abstract
 
  All-units discounts (AUD) are pricing schemes that lower a buyer’s marginal price on every unit purchased when the buyer’s purchase exceeds or is equal to a pre-specified threshold. The AUD and related conditional rebates are commonly used in both final-goods and intermediate-goods markets. Although the existing literature has thus far focused on interpreting the AUD as a price discrimination tool, investment incentive program, or rent-shifting instrument, the antitrust concerns on the AUD and related conditional rebates are often their plausible exclusionary effects.
    In this article, we investigate strategic effects of volume-threshold based AUD used by a dominant firm in the presence of a capacity-constrained rival. We find that the AUD always increase the dominant firm’s profits, sales volume and market share over linear pricing or two-part tariff. At the same time, the AUD adopted by a dominant firm lead to “partial foreclosure” of an equally or more efficient rival, in the sense that the rival’s profit, sales volume and market share are strictly reduced, as compared to linear pricing. The buyer’s surplus and total surplus could be either lower or higher under AUD, depending on the rival's capacity level relative to the demand size. The intuition for our findings is that, due to the limited capacity of the rival, the dominant firm, that has a “captive” portion of the buyer’s demand in the context of a single product, is able to use the AUD to leverage its market power on the “captive” to “competitive” portion of the demand, much like the tied-in selling strategy in the context of multiple products. Our analysis applies to other similar settings in which the dominant firm has some “captive” market when it offers “must-carry” brands or a wider range of products.
    
  “Pay-What-You-Want Pricing and Competition: Breaking the Bertrand the Bertrand Trap” with Jose Fernandez and Babu Nahata (Under Review)
 
  Abstract
    Under pay-what-you-want (PWYW) pricing, each consumer has total control over the price she wants to pay, which could potentially result in negative profits for the firm. In the standard Bertrand competition, two identical firms earn zero profits when they both charge the uniform price. We show that when one firm deviates and uses PWYW pricing, both firms could earn positive profits in equilibrium, breaking the so-called Bertrand trap. Although behavioral concerns are the driving factors for voluntary payments under PWYW, they may not always help the viability of PWYW pricing in the presence of competition.
 
 
  Abstract
    This paper examines competition between stock exchanges for order flow by setting make fees for limit orders and take fees for market orders. We find that exchanges can use make-take fees to create sub-tick prices and facilitate trades that are blocked by the tick size regulation. The discrete tick size generates two-sided markets in which the charge on each side matters even for the same total charge.
     Our two-sided market model explains several anomalies relative to a standard one-sided market. First, the breakdown of make-take fees is not neutral for social welfare, and the equilibrium fee structure always involves one side being subsidized and the other side being charged. Second, the price competition of two identical exchanges does not lead to Bertrand outcome, but to mixed strategy equilibrium with positive profits. This justifies the diversity of fee structures and their frequent adjustments, as well as the entry of exchanges with new fee structures. Third, the model predicts that liquidity makers prefer being charged (subsidized) when the tick size is large (small), and the market becomes more fragmented under a larger tick size. We find empirical evidence consistent with these two predictions using reverse splits of ETFs as exogenous shocks to the relative tick size, with paired ETFs that track the same index but do not reverse split as controls.
    
  “Allocations under Second-Degree Price Discrimination without Spence-Mirrlees Condition” with Babu Nahata
   
  “All-Units Discounts, Captive Demand, Foreclosure, and Inefficiency” with Guofu Tan
   
  “Bundled Loyalty Discount with Differentiated Products under Oligopoly
 
 
  “Three-Part Tariffs under Two-Dimensional Demand Uncertainties
 
 
  “Endogenous Entry Effects on Competition: Empirical Evidence from California Procurement Auctions”, Winner of Best Second-Year Paper Award at USC